[Speech]Economic Activity, Prices, and Monetary Policy in JapanSpeech at a Meeting with Local Leaders in Okinawa
NOGUCHI Asahi
Member of the Policy Board
June 22, 2023
I. Economic Activity and Prices
A. Economic Developments at Home and Abroad
I will begin my speech by talking about recent economic developments at home and abroad.
The global macroeconomic landscape has changed significantly with the COVID-19 pandemic that began in 2020 marking a divide: the global economy is now experiencing a high-inflation, high-interest rate environment more or less for the first time since the 1970s, having transformed from a low-inflation, low-interest rate environment known as secular stagnation. In the United States and Europe, rapid inflation began around spring 2021, when these economies began to emerge from the pandemic driven by widespread vaccination, and by 2022, inflation rates had reached around 8 to 10 percent (Chart 1). In this situation, central banks in these economies have rapidly raised their policy interest rates in order to contain high inflation (Chart 2). As I will touch on later, a tightening of labor market conditions that had taken place as economies began to emerge from the pandemic can be pointed to as background to the rapid inflation. However, labor market conditions have remained tight in these economies amid a moderate economic slowdown due to the policy interest rate hikes, and nominal wages have continued to rise at a pace above the historical trend. Given this situation, the monetary tightening phase is expected to continue, and the global economy is likely to continue decelerating for the time being (Chart 3).
I will now turn to developments in Japan's economy. The economy has continued to pick up as consumption, particularly in the face-to-face services industry, has been increasing moderately with the impact of COVID-19 waning, although exports and industrial production have been more or less flat amid the continued slowdown in overseas economies (Chart 4). As for the outlook, although such slowdown is likely to continue for some time, I expect Japan's economy to recover moderately on the back of the following factors: (1) further expansion in inbound tourism demand against the background of the yen's depreciation; (2) full-fledged normalization of the face-to-face services industry with the downgrading of COVID-19 to a Class V infectious disease; (3) easing of supply-side constraints that had remained in some areas, such as semiconductors; as well as (4) an expected expansion in business fixed investment due to Japanese manufacturers transferring their production sites back home and to labor-saving investment to address labor shortages.
Concerning risks to the outlook, overseas economies and global financial conditions warrant attention. As I mentioned earlier, overseas central banks have so far been raising their policy interest rates at a high pace in order to contain rapid inflation. Issues surrounding some financial institutions in the United States and Europe since March 2023, however, show that some overseas financial sectors have not necessarily been able to adequately respond to the recent changes in financial conditions (Chart 5). Such issues have not led to affecting the whole financial system, due in part to swift responses taken by the respective authorities. However, given that global macroeconomic conditions, triggered by the COVID-19 pandemic, have undergone a rapid change from a low-inflation, low-interest rate environment to a high-inflation, high-interest rate environment, there is a risk that some kind of financial shock would occur in an unexpected manner. Meanwhile, as high inflation has continued, mainly against the background of wage increases, central banks have not been able to change their monetary tightening stance. Such a situation is likely to make policy responses more difficult and create increasing uncertainties for the global economy.
B. Price Developments
Turning to Japan's price developments, the year-on-year rate of change in the consumer price index (CPI) for all items less fresh food continued to rise, exceeding 2 percent in April 2022, reaching 3 percent in September, and 4 percent in December (Chart 6). What triggered this inflation was a surge in energy prices that occurred in the process of a global recovery from a downturn caused by the pandemic. Moreover, since spring 2022, imported goods prices have risen across the board due to such factors as a further rise in international commodity prices that mainly reflected the situation in Ukraine, as well as the yen's depreciation during a situation of high global inflation and rising interest rates. Initially, the effects of such factors emerged mostly in the form of a rise in producer prices. However, since last summer, a pass-through of cost increases to selling prices at the retail level has also started to be observed, and moves to raise prices, particularly of food, have rapidly become widespread (Chart 7).
The year-on-year rate of change in the CPI, after having reached its peak at 4.2 percent in January 2023, has fallen to the range of 3 to 4 percent, due partly to a decline in energy prices owing to the government's support measures. However, as there seems to be a change in firms' price-setting stance, price rises, such as of food, are expected to continue for a while, and the situation of inflation exceeding 2 percent will likely remain for the time being, with a contribution mainly from rises in goods prices. Nonetheless, since the effects of import price rises will gradually dissipate as the pass-through of cost increases in the upstream of the distribution process to the downstream peaks out, the year-on-year rate of change in the CPI for all items less fresh food is expected to fall below 2 percent toward the middle of fiscal 2023.
Subsequent to the slowdown, in order for the year-on-year rate of change to accelerate again toward 2 percent and stay at such a level, it is important that the underlying trend in prices rise. As I will describe in more detail later on, in terms of the outlook, I am paying particular attention to developments in nominal wages and services prices. In this regard, the fact that wage increases at the highest level in about 30 years were achieved in the 2023 annual spring labor-management wage negotiations holds important implications. Although this year's negotiation results were prompted by global inflation, which is an exogenous factor, they could be suggesting that improvement in labor market conditions brought about by the Bank of Japan's patient conduct of monetary easing has finally started to bear fruit in the form of a synergy between price rises and wage increases.
II. Monetary Policy
A. Conduct of Yield Curve Control
Let me now turn to the Bank of Japan's policy conduct. In order to overcome prolonged deflation and achieve the price stability target of 2 percent, the Bank introduced quantitative and qualitative monetary easing (QQE) in April 2013. Thereafter, in order to enhance monetary easing while responding to developments in economic activity and prices, it introduced QQE with a Negative Interest Rate in January 2016, and QQE with Yield Curve Control in September. Under this so-called yield curve control policy, the Bank set the target level of 10-year Japanese government bonds (JGB) yields at "around zero percent" and, in practice, such yields had been in the range of around plus and minus 0.1 percent. Thereafter, given that market transactions were sluggish because of the narrow range of yield fluctuations, in July 2018, the Bank decided that the yields may move upward and downward to some extent, mainly depending on developments in economic activity and prices, with a specific figure of "about double the range of around plus and minus 0.1 percentage points" in mind. Moreover, given the findings of the Assessment for Further Effective and Sustainable Monetary Easing conducted in March 2021, the Bank made clear that the range of 10-year JGB yield fluctuations from the target level would be "between around plus and minus 0.25 percentage points." In December 2022, it was further expanded to "between around plus and minus 0.5 percentage points."
In this way, the Bank has been expanding the range of 10-year JGB yield fluctuations from the target level under the yield curve control policy. This is because, while long-term interest rates need to be kept stable at low levels in order to achieve the 2 percent price stability target, holding down such rates also could affect market functioning. Meanwhile, in the case where the range of 10-year JGB yield fluctuations from the target level is expanded so as to ensure market functioning, long-term interest rates could rise as a result, leading to a less accommodative monetary environment and a delay in economic recovery. The management of 10-year JGB yield fluctuations therefore needs to be considered based on the judgment of the trade-off between monetary easing effects at a macroeconomic level and effects on market functioning, among others.
The Bank's decision to expand the range of 10-year JGB yield fluctuations from the target level in December 2022 also was made based on such judgment. In 2022, as a result of economic recovery in various countries and regions, inflation accelerated and interest rates rose globally. These developments also affected Japan, as was seen in the 10-year JGB yields approaching 0.25 percent -- the upper limit of the yield curve control policy of the time -- in March 2022. The Bank subsequently took measures, such as devising its conduct of JGB purchase operations, and prevented a heightening of long-term interest rates, which potentially could have hindered Japan's economic recovery. At the same time, these measures caused marked distortions in the yield curve. The shape of the JGB yield curve, however, is now generally smooth due to the measures taken in December 2022 to expand the range of 10-year JGB yield fluctuations, the various deliberations with regard to its JGB purchase operations, and, furthermore, in part to the recent global decline in interest rates (Chart 8).
B. Policy Responses to COVID-19 and Forward Guidance
At the Monetary Policy Meeting (MPM) held in March 2020, when COVID-19 started to exert a severe impact on Japan's economy, the Bank decided to take three measures, including the Special Program to Support Financing in Response to the Novel Coronavirus (COVID-19) (the Special Program), and it has continued with them through the addition of amendments (Chart 9). Concurrently, the Bank introduced a forward guidance that it will closely monitor the impact of COVID-19 for the time being and will not hesitate to take additional easing measures if necessary, and as for the policy rates, the Bank added that it expects short- and long-term interest rates to remain at their present or lower levels.
Although the risk of a resurgence of COVID-19 remains, the pandemic, after three years since its outbreak, is finally becoming a thing of the past. At the same time, I would like to reiterate that uncertainties surrounding economies and financial markets at home and abroad have become extremely high. In view of such situation, at the April 2023 MPM, the Bank deleted the description associated with the pandemic from its forward guidance for monetary policy and made clear its stance that it "will patiently continue with monetary easing while nimbly responding to developments in economic activity and prices as well as financial conditions. By doing so, it will aim to achieve the price stability target of 2 percent in a sustainable and stable manner, accompanied by wage increases." The new guidance shows the Bank's strong commitment to patiently maintain its monetary accommodation, with a continued aim to achieve the price stability target in a sustainable and stable manner.
C. Broad-Perspective Review of Monetary Policy
Also at its April 2023 MPM, the Bank decided to conduct a broad-perspective review of monetary policy, with a planned time frame of around one to one and a half years. It will go over the various monetary easing measures it has implemented with the aim of achieving price stability since the late 1990s, when Japan's economy fell into deflation. The direction of the review is entirely a matter for upcoming discussions, but in what follows I would like to underscore two points that I personally feel are particularly germane.
The first is the importance of an international perspective. One focus of the review will be to reassess the Bank's unconventional monetary policy measures, starting with quantitative easing. The Bank was compelled to put these measures in place by an urgent situation in which the country was poised to slide into deflation but there was virtually no scope for the traditional means of lowering the short-term policy interest rate. In the wake of the Global Financial Crisis and the COVID-19 pandemic, however, many major central banks have come up against similar constraints on their ability to control short-term interest rates and have shifted toward a strategy of purchasing more assets to apply an easing effect to financial conditions more broadly, including real long-term interest rates. The upshot is that the basic monetary policy frameworks of major central banks now involve a two-pronged approach of adjusting short-term policy interest rates and purchasing assets using their own balance sheets. In other words, the very measures that were called unconventional 10 years ago have now become global standard practice. The Bank of Japan turned out to be the forerunner of this trend.
The second point involves a situation that is unique to Japan, which is the influence of people's perception of prices, called norms. Many central banks are currently having to grapple with high inflation. What this actually means is that the recoveries sparked by their expansionary policy responses were unexpectedly robust. By contrast, although Japan was the first to introduce an unconventional monetary easing policy, it is still the farthest away from exiting such easing. This is ostensibly due to the fact that, when deflation or zero inflation persists for too long, as it did in Japan, this state becomes the fixed norm -- that is, the normative belief -- and displacing such a norm becomes extremely difficult. In fact, in many advanced economies like the United States and Europe, popular inflation expectations are generally consistent with the nominal anchor inflation target, but in Japan, they are not anchored to the 2 percent target (Chart 10). This is considered to be one reason why the price stability target has not been achieved in Japan.
III. Aiming for a Virtuous Cycle between Prices and Wages
A. Why Price Stability Needs to Be Accompanied by Higher Wages
The impact of global inflation has extended to prices in Japan as well, through rises in commodity and energy prices, for example. As I mentioned earlier, in Japan, the year-on-year rate of change in the CPI for all items excluding fresh food has been above 2 percent since the spring of 2022, exceeding 4 percent at the start of this year. Even so, while other central banks have moved forward with rapid monetary tightening to contain high inflation, the Bank of Japan has patiently continued with monetary easing. This reflects the fact that the inflation seen in Japan since spring 2022 is basically due to the rise in imported goods prices. The Bank has therefore judged that the underlying trend in prices, which is the inflation trend based on Japan's domestic macroeconomic factors, has not yet risen enough.
In speeches and on other occasions, the Bank has long stressed that, to achieve the price stability target of 2 percent in a sustainable and stable manner, price increases must be accompanied by wage increases.1 Judging the current situation from this perspective, although consumer prices may rise temporarily on the back of cost-push factors from overseas, unless the underlying inflation trend itself converges on the 2 percent target accompanied by wage increases, it is considered highly likely that inflation will fall back below 2 percent once the temporary factors subside.
In terms of which prices we consider key in trying to discern price trends, among the items making up the CPI -- rather than, for example, energy prices, which are subject to significant fluctuations -- it is important to pay more attention to trends in services prices, which are both less volatile and more sticky. Services prices are better indicators of underlying price movements because they more closely reflect movements in highly sticky wages, which account for the bulk of the cost of services.2 In other words, if there is a given uptrend in wages, there will also tend to be a given uptrend in prices themselves, mainly through the contribution of services prices.3
The importance of services items in the underlying inflation trend is also apparent in the decomposition of factors affecting consumer prices (Chart 11). In the United States, before COVID-19, the contribution of goods prices to changes in the CPI was extremely limited, indicating that increases in the CPI were almost entirely driven by higher services prices. It is also clear that the contribution of services prices to inflation was relatively large in Europe. In the post-pandemic phase, we first saw inflation expand on the back of higher prices of both energy and goods, and then a gradual transition to inflation driven by services prices in the United States and Europe, as the contributions of energy and goods prices diminished.
The above factors suggest that services prices and the wages that lie behind them are keys to understanding the underlying trend in inflation.
- For example, see Kuroda, H., "Japan's Economy and Monetary Policy: Toward Overcoming Deflation," speech at a meeting held by the Naigai Josei Chousa Kai (Research Institute of Japan) in Tokyo, July 29, 2013, and "Toward Achieving the Price Stability Target in a Sustainable and Stable Manner, Accompanied by Wage Increases," speech at the meeting of Councillors of Keidanren (Japan Business Federation) in Tokyo, December 26, 2022.
- In a November 2022 speech, Federal Reserve Chair Jerome H. Powell pointed out that, in discerning underlying price movements, it was critical to look at the core inflation rate, which excludes the impact of food and energy. Furthermore, of particular importance among core inflation components were core services other than housing, which cover "a wide range of services from health care and education to haircuts and hospitality. . . . Because wages make up the largest cost in delivering these services, the labor market holds the key to understanding inflation in this category" in the United States. See Jerome H. Powell, "Inflation and the Labor Market," speech at the Hutchins Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy, Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C., November 30, 2022.
- Since the real wage growth rate is virtually identical to the labor productivity growth rate over the long term, the inflation rate is considered to trend at a level that is equal to the difference between the nominal wage growth rate and the labor productivity growth rate.
B. Nominal Wages Finally Starting to Rise
As of June 2023, inflation in the United States and Europe continues to significantly exceed the target rate of 2 percent. This is because -- although the rates of increase in consumer prices seem to have peaked out as energy prices have declined -- services prices, which are sticky, have continued to rise faster than the trend in prices due to the tightening of labor market conditions. In this situation, the Federal Reserve and the European Central Bank (ECB) have announced that they will continue with monetary tightening to suppress aggregate demand until it becomes possible to truly envisage the 2 percent inflation rate being achieved.4
The current situation of Japan's labor market, however, differs greatly from the aforementioned situation in the United States and Europe. Indeed, the rate of increase in services prices has recently started to accelerate in Japan as well, but this is mainly attributable to price increases such as of food and electricity, and thus the effects of the rise in wage costs have not been that strong so far. Although it is said that Japan is facing labor shortage, a tightening of labor market conditions such as those seen in the United States and Europe has not been observed, at least not statistically. Since 2021 in the United States, not only has there been a decline in the unemployment rate -- which surged during the pandemic -- but the job vacancy rate has increased rapidly. As a result, the ratio of job openings to unemployment, which had stood at around 0.7 on average since the 2000s, has risen to a high of around 2 (Chart 12). In contrast, the unemployment rate and the active job openings-to-applicants ratio in Japan still have not recovered to pre-pandemic levels as of June 2023 (Chart 13).
Despite the recovery being only moderate, the situation for Japan's labor market differs from that seen in the past in terms of wage increases, especially since the turn of this year. This is best demonstrated by the results of the 2023 annual spring labor-management wage negotiations. The rate of increase in wages -- which is increases in regular salaries and base pay combined -- is in the range of 3.5-4.0 percent based on the results available to date, marking the highest level in about 30 years (Chart 14). However, even at this level, the rate of increase in base pay merely exceeds 2 percent, which is extremely low compared to the wage growth in the United States and Europe. Still, this increase in wages represents the largest rate of increase achieved in a year since 1980, and it can be viewed as a favorable development for realizing a virtuous cycle between prices and wages.
- 4Federal Reserve Chair Powell pointed out in the aforementioned speech that, "in the labor market, demand for workers far exceeds the supply of available workers, and nominal wages have been growing at a pace well above what would be consistent with 2 percent inflation over time." He then noted that "for the near term, a moderation of labor demand growth will be required to restore balance to the labor market." ECB President Christine Lagarde also stated in her speech in March 2023 that it is necessary to suppress demand in order to prevent price rises caused by further wage increases. See Christine Lagarde, "The Path Ahead," speech at "The ECB and Its Watchers XXIII" conference, Frankfurt am Main, March 22, 2023.
C. Shift in the Price and Wage Norm Triggered by a Big Push
Despite considerable improvement in labor market conditions, nominal wages in Japan have not risen sufficiently. If it is true that market mechanisms determine nominal wages, then such wages should tend to rise if job openings expand vis-à-vis job seekers, causing an increase in the active job openings-to-applicants ratio, which is the ratio of labor demand to labor supply. In the United States, a clear correlation between job openings to unemployment and nominal wage growth can, in fact, be observed. In Japan, however, since the late 1990s, when the country entered a deflationary period, no such clear correlation between the job openings-to-applicants ratio and nominal wage growth has been found. Focusing solely at the 2010s -- including the years from 2013, when the Bank introduced QQE -- growth in nominal wages remained negligible even though the job openings-to-applicants ratio continued to rise more or less by itself up until immediately before the outbreak of the pandemic (Chart 15).
This situation seems to have been attributable to various factors. Perhaps the most pertinent is the zero price and wage norm that has been the normative belief of firms and households regarding prices and wages. Although the Bank's conduct of monetary easing helped Japan overcome the deflation that had continued since the late 1990s, in the sense of a sustained decline in prices, the price stability target accompanied by wage increases has not been achieved. This is likely owing to the experience of Japanese firms during the prolonged period of stagnation, which saw mounting instances of price hikes leading directly to sales declines. Firms thus came to prioritize a stance of maintaining stable selling prices by holding down wage costs.5 This seems to have caused the zero price and wage norm -- the belief that both prices and wages do not rise -- to take root among firms and households.
This zero price and wage norm, which had been deeply entrenched, seems to finally be shifting under the impact of a so-called big push -- an exogenous shock from the rise in imported goods prices stemming from global inflation. In stark contrast to the past, firms across the board are now passing on the higher costs of imported raw materials to selling prices, even at the retail level. The likelihood that the price and wage norm seems to be shifting is indicated most of all by the first real increase in the CPI since the 1980s. Of course, this increase is basically due to cost-push factors and therefore will not directly lead to an increase in underlying prices. Nevertheless, if these developments go on to encourage firms to pass on costs, including wage costs, to selling prices, in turn inducing further wage hikes, this will push up the underlying inflation trend (Chart 16).
One possible way of understanding why wage hikes have not quite materialized is that, while firms found it difficult to pass on wage hikes to prices, they had tended in particular to refrain from increasing the wages of regular employees, who are less likely to leave their jobs.6 Nonetheless, improvements in labor market conditions brought about by the Bank's patient conduct of monetary easing to date have already begun to step up the pressure on firms to raise wages of regular employees, both in terms of the external pressure to curb turnover and of the internal pressure to ensure fairness among peers.7 In this regard, the recent big push may have literally acted as a decisive factor driving this year's wage negotiations.
- 5See Aoki, K., Hogen, Y., and Takatomi, K., "Price Markups and Wage Setting Behavior of Japanese Firms," Bank of Japan Working Paper Series, no. 23-E-5 (April 2023). This paper, by using the data from fiscal 2005 to 2020, explains that, during this period, Japanese firms had reduced their price markups -- in which they pass on costs to selling prices -- while they had increased their price markdowns -- in which they hold down wages to avoid price rises.
- 6For more details, see Fukunaga, I. et al., "Wage Developments in Japan: Four Key Issues for the Post-COVID-19 Wage Growth," Bank of Japan Working Paper Series, no. 23-E-4 (March 2023).
- 7For a study on external and internal pressure on wages, see Furukawa, K., Hogen, Y., and Kido, Y., "Labor Market of Regular Workers in Japan: A Perspective from Job Advertisement Data," Bank of Japan Working Paper Series, no. 23-E-7 (April 2023).
D. Outlook for Sustainable Wage Increases
The key issue now is to lock in the momentum behind wage hikes that is finally beginning to gather as a result of continued monetary easing, and to establish this as a lasting trend. If this happens, it should at last bring back the kind of economic growth based on a virtuous cycle between prices and wages that has long been missing from Japan's economic landscape. The ultimate goal of the Bank's patient conduct of monetary easing is to restore Japan's economy to this state.
Meanwhile, for Japan's economy to continue growing and for real incomes to continue increasing steadily, raising labor productivity through technological advances is essential. This is basically the purview of individual private firms and their efforts in the areas of research and development and the improvement of business and production processes. The role of monetary policy is simply to encourage these endeavors by providing accommodative financial conditions.8
It is important to note, however, that Japanese firms have by no means neglected to make such efforts. In the 2010s, at least, although Japan's economic growth rate as a whole clearly remained only moderate, owing to ongoing declines in the population and in working hours, Japan nevertheless outperformed the United States in terms of GDP growth per hour worked (Chart 17).
These developments suggest the real likelihood of continued steady growth in Japan's economy, accompanied by productivity gains. The fundamental issue lies in the fact that the zero price and wage norm has become entrenched in Japan over a prolonged period of deflation and excessively low inflation, and the fact that we have not yet achieved a virtuous cycle between prices and wages. The Bank, for the time being, should carefully assess whether or not this norm is on the verge of being shifted.
Thank you.
- 8Some economists argue that monetary policy brings about positive effects on productivity indirectly. For example, according to the theory of high-pressure economics put forth by Arthur M. Okun and Janet L. Yellen, if macroeconomic policies bring about tighter labor market conditions, investment in labor saving will expand, which will result in a further increase in labor productivity (see also Chart 16). For more details, see Arthur M. Okun, "Upward Mobility in a High-Pressure Economy," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no.1 (1973), and Janet L. Yellen, "Macroeconomic Research after the Crisis," remarks at the 60th annual economic conference sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston titled "The Elusive 'Great' Recovery: Causes and Implications for Future Business Cycle Dynamics," October 14, 2016.