Rank-index method
A joint Politics and Economics series |
Social choice and electoral systems |
---|
Single vote - plurality methods
|
By results of combination
By mechanism of combination By ballot type |
|
icon Mathematics portal |
In apportionment theory, rank-index methods[1] : Sec.8 are a set of apportionment methods that generalize the divisor method. These have also been called Huntington methods,[2] since they generalize an idea by Edward Vermilye Huntington.
Input and output
[edit ]Like all apportionment methods, the inputs of any rank-index method are:
- A positive integer {\displaystyle h} representing the total number of items to allocate. It is also called the house size.
- A positive integer {\displaystyle n} representing the number of agents to which items should be allocated. For example, these can be federal states or political parties.
- A vector of fractions {\displaystyle (t_{1},\ldots ,t_{n})} with {\displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{n}t_{i}=1}, representing entitlements - {\displaystyle t_{i}} represents the entitlement of agent {\displaystyle i}, that is, the fraction of items to which {\displaystyle i} is entitled (out of the total of {\displaystyle h}).
Its output is a vector of integers {\displaystyle a_{1},\ldots ,a_{n}} with {\displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{n}a_{i}=h}, called an apportionment of {\displaystyle h}, where {\displaystyle a_{i}} is the number of items allocated to agent i.
Iterative procedure
[edit ]Every rank-index method is parametrized by a rank-index function {\displaystyle r(t,a)}, which is increasing in the entitlement {\displaystyle t} and decreasing in the current allocation {\displaystyle a}. The apportionment is computed iteratively as follows:
- Initially, set {\displaystyle a_{i}} to 0 for all parties.
- At each iteration, allocate one item to an agent for whom {\displaystyle r(t_{i},a_{i})} is maximum (break ties arbitrarily).
- Stop after {\displaystyle h} iterations.
Divisor methods are a special case of rank-index methods: a divisor method with divisor function {\displaystyle d(a)} is equivalent to a rank-index method with rank-index function {\displaystyle r(t,a)=t/d(a)}.
Min-max formulation
[edit ]Every rank-index method can be defined using a min-max inequality: a is an allocation for the rank-index method with function r, if-and-only-if:[1] : Thm.8.1
{\displaystyle \min _{i:a_{i}>0}r(t_{i},a_{i}-1)\geq \max _{i}r(t_{i},a_{i})}.
Properties
[edit ]Every rank-index method is house-monotone. This means that, when {\displaystyle h} increases, the allocation of each agent weakly increases. This immediately follows from the iterative procedure.
Every rank-index method is uniform. This means that, we take some subset of the agents {\displaystyle 1,\ldots ,k}, and apply the same method to their combined allocation, then the result is exactly the vector {\displaystyle (a_{1},\ldots ,a_{k})}. In other words: every part of a fair allocation is fair too. This immediately follows from the min-max inequality.
Moreover:
- Every apportionment method that is uniform, symmetric and balanced must be a rank-index method.[1] : Thm.8.3
- Every apportionment method that is uniform, house-monotone and balanced must be a rank-index method.[2]
Quota-capped divisor methods
[edit ]A quota-capped divisor method is an apportionment method where we begin by assigning every state its lower quota of seats. Then, we add seats one-by-one to the state with the highest votes-per-seat average, so long as adding an additional seat does not result in the state exceeding its upper quota.[3] However, quota-capped divisor methods violate the participation criterion (also called population monotonicity)—it is possible for a party to lose a seat as a result of winning more votes.[4] : Tbl.A7.2
Every quota-capped divisor method satisfies house monotonicity. Moreover, quota-capped divisor methods satisfy the quota rule.[5] : Thm.7.1
However, quota-capped divisor methods violate the participation criterion (also called population monotonicity)—it is possible for a party to lose a seat as a result of winning more votes.[5] : Tbl.A7.2 This occurs when:
- Party i gets more votes.
- Because of the greater divisor, the upper quota of some other party j decreases. Therefore, party j is not eligible to a seat in the current iteration, and some third party receives the seat instead.
- Then, at the next iteration, party j is again eligible to win a seat and it beats party i.
Moreover, quota-capped versions of other algorithms frequently violate the true quota in the presence of error (e.g. census miscounts). Jefferson's method frequently violates the true quota, even after being quota-capped, while Webster's method and Huntington-Hill perform well even without quota-caps.[6]
References
[edit ]- ^ a b c Balinski, Michel L.; Young, H. Peyton (1982). Fair Representation: Meeting the Ideal of One Man, One Vote . New Haven: Yale University Press. ISBN 0-300-02724-9.
- ^ a b Balinski, M. L.; Young, H. P. (1977年12月01日). "On Huntington Methods of Apportionment". SIAM Journal on Applied Mathematics. 33 (4): 607–618. doi:10.1137/0133043. ISSN 0036-1399.
- ^ Balinski, M. L.; Young, H. P. (1975年08月01日). "The Quota Method of Apportionment". The American Mathematical Monthly. 82 (7): 701–730. doi:10.1080/00029890.1975.11993911. ISSN 0002-9890.
- ^ Balinski, Michel L.; Young, H. Peyton (1982). Fair Representation: Meeting the Ideal of One Man, One Vote . New Haven: Yale University Press. ISBN 0-300-02724-9.
- ^ a b Balinski, Michel L.; Young, H. Peyton (1982). Fair Representation: Meeting the Ideal of One Man, One Vote . New Haven: Yale University Press. ISBN 0-300-02724-9.
- ^ Spencer, Bruce D. (December 1985). "Statistical Aspects of Equitable Apportionment". Journal of the American Statistical Association. 80 (392): 815–822. doi:10.1080/01621459.1985.10478188. ISSN 0162-1459.